EU Economy
ECB monetary policy still tight for Southern Europe
By Michael Hennigan, editor and founder of Finfacts
Aug 10, 2015 - 3:59 AM

Printer-friendly page from Finfacts Ireland Business News - Click for the News Main Page - A service of the Finfacts Ireland Business and Finance Portal

Despite almost zero interest rates and quantitative easing (bond-buying in the market, commonly known as money printing) provided by the European Central Bank (ECB) in recent times, monetary policy remains tight for Southern Europe.

Deutsche Bank economists say it is the classic dilemma of any currency union that a single monetary policy cannot possibly be appropriate for everybody if members are at very different stages of the business cycle — it has also been a challenge in an individual country such as the UK in the past where the Bank of England had to contend with signs of an overheating regional economy in London and England's South-east while economic conditions were more subdued elsewhere.

Thomas Meyer and Anamaria Piloiu write that to get a feel for the scale of monetary (mis-)alignment, "we calculate central bank rates as implied by a modified Taylor rule.* For the euro area as a whole, this rate (the yellow dotted line in the chart) is fairly close to the actual main refinancing rate set by the ECB. This suggests that monetary conditions have on average been quite fitting. However, the picture changes when looking at individual regions."

The economists say that naturally, the regions of interest are what is commonly referred to as core European Monetary Union [EMU] (e.g. Germany, the Netherlands and Finland) and the periphery (Italy, Spain, Greece, Ireland, and Portugal). As illustrated in the chart, the monetary needs of the core and the periphery as implied by the Taylor rule have been very different throughout the history of EMU.

"Currently, monetary conditions appear to be too lax in the core but too tight in the periphery."

The economists say that this form of misalignment is a destabilising force on EMU because it tends to exacerbate differences in business cycles, thus putting more strain on fiscal and macro-prudential policy. Moreover, monetary misalignment often breeds future problems. Before the financial crisis, monetary conditions were too generous in the periphery, contributing to an unsustainable credit boom, rising public and private debt and inflated real estate prices. This made the post-crisis hangover even more painful.

"Of course, the Taylor rule is only a rough guide to central bank rates," the economists say. "One of its key drivers, the output or unemployment gap, is only known in hindsight and not in real time. Moreover, the rule does not take into account unconventional monetary policies, such as quantitative easing. It also ignores that in times of crisis lack of access to credit is often more important than the level of interest rates. Yet, despite these caveats, it seems fair to say that monetary policy in EMU needs to strike a delicate balance."

*The Taylor rule (as described by Ben Bernanke, former chairman of the Federal Reserve) is a guide for setting key central bank rates proposed by John B. Taylor of Stanford University and others in 1993. The modified rule used here calculates the appropriate central bank rate based on core inflation rates and the unemployment gap (giving both equal weights) for each country.

Is Euro Area Ireland's top trading partner?: EU28 is overwhelmingly UK's

Budget surpluses rare in developed countries from 1980s; Italy, France, Greece had none in 60 and 40 years

Irish standard of living in 2014 below Euro Area average, Italian level; Prices 5th highest in EU28

German car firms boost exports from Spain, UK, Portugal, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary and Romania

Krugman calls euro a Roach Motel; Hotel California gets 1-star grade

Irish lessons for Greece on growing exports and investment


© Copyright 2015 by Finfacts.ie